World’s Most Misaligned Currencies – Dollar, Yen, and Euro for Germany

Any country that devalues their currency in order to take unfair advantage of the United States, which is many countries, will be met with sharply. And that includes tariffs and taxes. –Candidate Trump, Pennsylvania, 6/28/16

[John R. Hansen | July 7, 2017 | ABCD Now]

Messages like this resonated with voters across the nation during the Presidential Campaign. “Foreigners are manipulating their currencies” and “currency manipulation is destroying American factories and jobs” have been the rallying cries. 

Currency manipulation has indeed created serious problems for the competitiveness of factories and farms across America, especially during the period 2003-2013, the “Decade of Manipulation” as Fred Bergsten and Joe Gagnon have called it in Chapter 4 of their new book, Currency Conflict and Trade Policy.  But we must keep in mind two very important facts. 

First, even during this period, private capital flows greatly exceeded public capital flows into the United States (Figure 1). There is no evidence that an open-market purchase of $100 billion of U.S. securities by the Chinese Government would have any more impact on the dollar’s exchange rate than an equal purchase by Deutsche Bank AG of Germany. Thus, even during the “Decade of Manipulation,” excessive private capital flows into the United States clearly had a larger impact on the dollar’s exchange rate than did currency manipulation.

Figure 1

Off.Pvt.80-.png

Second, the Decade of Manipulation ended about four years ago, but the US trade deficit still amounts to hundreds of billions of dollars per year because the U.S. dollar is still so sharply overvalued.

This note uses the latest data from the IMF and the Peterson Institute for International Economics (PIIE) to show (a) the severity of the dollar’s overvaluation, and (b) the uniqueness of this overvaluation — which is truly a one-of-a-kind situation for the entire world.

Among the currencies of the countries accounting for the large majority of US trade — and almost all of its trade deficits, the dollar is the only currency that is significantly overvalued — and it is overvalued by a massive 25.5 percent (Table 1, column 7). No wonder the US suffers serious trade deficits. [1]

Table 1
_P1.png

The Mexican peso is the only other overvalued currency in this group. This is notable for two reasons.  First, Mexico is one of the four most prominent sources of US trade deficits — along with China, Germany, and Japan. Consequently, many claim that Mexico is guilty of extensive currency manipulation and that the peso is seriously undervalued. Totally wrong. Mexico actually runs a significant global trade deficit, indicating that the peso is over-valued. All of the talk about currency manipulation in connection with the announced renegotiation of NAFTA is therefore way off the mark. Currency undervaluation has nothing to do with Mexico’s trade surplus with the United States.

Second, the US dollar is four times more overvalued than the Mexican peso is. This leads directly to the conclusion that America’s annual trade deficit of roughly $60 billion with Mexico is the result of the overvaluation of the dollar, not the undervaluation of the peso.

Now let’s look at the other currencies, all of which are undervalued compared to the exchange rate — the Fundamental Equilibrium Exchange rate or FEER that would be consistent with balanced trade the each of these countries. 

Germany and Japan. These stand out because their currencies are roughly as undervalued as the dollar is overvalued. [2]

China. Another point worth noting in Table 1 is the low “Total REER Misalignment” of the Chinese yuan. At less than five percent, this is only one fifth of the misalignment of the US dollar. 

Which raises an obvious question: If China’s calculated currency misalignment is so relatively small, why is America’s trade deficit with China so much larger than its trade deficit with countries like Japan, Germany and Mexico. 

This question is a big one — too big, in fact, for the space available here, so I will explore it in a separate blog post. Here I only note some tentative thoughts about causal factors: 

(a) Size Matters. With a labor force of 800 million, China can easily produce more goods than any other country. 

(b) Domestic Economies of Scale. With a population of 1.3 billion that is rapidly becoming urbanized with higher incomes, Chinese factories can achieve economies of scale just in the domestic market that no other country can hope to match. These economies of scale make it possible to export at markedly lower prices. 

(c) State Production Controls: China’s system of state capitalism, involving both SOE’s and a heavy state hand on private enterprise, allows China to control production decisions — and to subsidize production — in ways that are impossible in normal market economies. 

(d) Trade Policies. China clearly manipulates access to its domestic market with tariff and non-tariff barriers, making it very difficult for America to sell the volume of exports needed to balance America’s imports from China. 

Korea. The Korean yuan is less out of line with its trade-balancing equilibrium exchange rate, but its undervaluation is still very significant. Like China, it is not guilty under IMF rules of active currency manipulation today. However, the misalignment of these currencies clearly results from (a) past manipulation, (b) highly successful industrial development based in large measure on the protection offered by earlier currency manipulation, and (c) the failure of global currency markets to bring these currencies into line with their equilibrium rates. Given such market failures, which have been a major problem over the past 40-plus years since the start of the OPEC oil crises, the only sure way to correct such misalignments is a proactive currency adjustment policy such as the Market Access Charge that the US can control directly — and still be fully in line with IMF and WTO rules.

Canada. Canada is included in this discussion only because it is a member of NAFTA and therefore is involved in NAFTA restructuring discussions. Although the US does run a small trade deficit with Canada, this is a non-issue for two reasons. First, the deficit is small — only $11 billion in 2016. Second, the Canadian dollar is almost perfectly aligned with its trade-balancing equilibrium exchange rate.

Conclusion

Fighting currency manipulation, which seems to be the recipe trotted out whenever US trade deficits are discussed, will do virtually nothing to fix the 25.5 percent overvaluation of the US dollar. This is the elephant in the room that few American politicians and policy makers seem willing to look in the eye and fix with a pro-active tool like the MAC. 

Until this happens, America will continue to suffer rising trade deficits, lost jobs, dying factories, and debt for future generations.

America needs instead to move as quickly as possible to implement a MAC — the only tool specifically designed to bring the dollar to its trade balancing equilibrium exchange rate in an automatic, measured way. This is critically important because … 

America Needs a Competitive Dollar Now 

John R. Hansen
July 7, 2017

Details of the calculations behind the countries shown in Table 1 above plus detailed calculations for nearly 30 other significant US trading partners are available. See the Technical Notes section that follows the Footnotes below.  

Footnotes

[1] The “Interpreting the Columns” box below the table provides a number for each column for easy identification. The “Current Table Column Number” line, shows the source of the data. “IMF” and “Cline” refer to the sources noted immediately above; the actual data are provided in the detailed Tables 1 and 2 in the document linked at the end of this note. Entries such as “C1/C2” indicate the source by column for the indicators I calculated based on data from the IMF and Cline data shown in previous columns. For example, the data in Column 3 was calculated for each line by dividing the entry in Column 1 by the entry in Column 2.  An entry such as “$C7/C7 for the “Ratio of U.S. to Partner Misalignment” indicates that the numbers for that column were calculated by dividing the US$ overvaluation number in Column 7 by the over or under valuation for the given country in the same column.   

[2]  It would be convenient to be able to directly add the dollar’s overvaluation to the undervaluation of the currencies of Germany or of Japan so that we could talk some kind of gross currency misalignment. However, this is not so easy because the adjustments shown in columns 2, 6, and 7 are specific to each currency against its own trade-balancing fundamental equilibrium exchange rate (FEER), not against a trade-weighted index of other currencies.

The overvaluation of the dollar is reflected in, for example, the undervaluation of the yen. Consequently, adding up the misalignments would lead to some double-counting. However, the ratios of US to partner currency misalignment shown in column 8 make it clear that except for Germany and Japan, the overvaluation of the dollar dominates the total misalignment of currencies. 

Technical Notes

The table above summarizes results from a series of tables available here that show the entire process of calculating the severity of the dollar’s overvaluation as well as the misalignment of 33 other countries as well.  For a more complete understanding of the derivation of the above currency misalignment estimates based on true-zero current account balances, download these tables by clicking here, then review the following table-by-table explanations.
 
Table 1 shows the original IMF data that Cline starts with for his semi-annual reports on Estimates of Fundamental Equilibrium Exchange Rates. These data come primarily from the annual IMF External Sector Report.
 
Table 2 reflects Cline’s revision of the data based on updated information. The revised data are then used in the Symmetric Matrix Inversion Method (SMIM) model that he developed in 2008 to calculate the adjustments in current exchange rates needed to accomplish current account balances targeted for five years out — 2022 for the latest projections). 
 
Note that the adjustment is calculated separately for each country with respect to its fundamental equilibrium exchange rate (FEER), not with respect to the currency of any other country. Thus the adjustment for country X cannot be added to the adjustment required for the United States to get some kind of estimate of the total percentage price disadvantage facing US producers, or to translate these figures into adjustments required with respect to the US dollar. 
 
In recent years, the PIIE estimates have moved away from the misleading practice of treating the US dollar as the numeraire, then calculating adjustments for all other countries while leaving the value of the dollar unchanged. That presentation made it look as though the dollar was the center of the monetary universe, and that all other currencies had to adjust to a standard that was “always right.” Now the PIIE analysis makes it very clear that the dollar itself can be seriously misaligned, and that it may also need to adjust.   
 
The target current account balance for five years out (2022 for the current numbers) basically assumes that any balance between -3% and +3% of GDP is “close enough” — and even “allows” targeted current account balances considerably larger for “special” cases like oil producing countries (implying that leaving oil in the ground that is not needed today is not an option). 
 
Table 3. Like many others, I find a +/- 3% of GDP targeting economically, socially, and politically unacceptable as a basis for planning America’s future. This basically assumes that we should continue to serve as the dumping ground for excess production from other countries, and that we should burden our children and grandchildren with a growing debt to foreign countries. 
 
Furthermore, the +/- 3% of GDP target implies that America (and other deficit countries) should bear the burden of increasing unemployment by up to 3% so that other countries can enjoy full employment and mercantilist trade surpluses. In the United States, this implies the unemployment of well over three million people! Not acceptable.
 
I have therefore recalculated the PIIE numbers according to a methodology that Bill Cline kindly suggested to me. This recalculation, which provides to core of Table 3, replaces the +/- 3% of GDP target — and any other non-zero targets — with a true zero current account balance target. 
 
This process provides us with the 25.5 percent exchange rate overvaluation shown for the United States in Table 1 above, and in the detailed Table 3.  A true zero current account balance would eliminate the US trade deficit, allowing America to enjoy the fullest possible utilization of its labor and capital resources.

MADE IN AMERICA.

CPA is the leading national, bipartisan organization exclusively representing domestic producers and workers across many industries and sectors of the U.S. economy.

The latest CPA news and updates, delivered every Friday.

WATCH: WE ARE CPA

Get the latest in CPA news, industry analysis, opinion, and updates from Team CPA.